Everybody now knows the narrative of the Great Financial Recession of
2008, in particular, the impact that toxic derivatives had in terms of
exacerbating the crisis. And the usual defense of those who
misdiagnosed the crisis is that the very nature of the so-called "shadow
banking system" made it difficult to determine the systemic nature of
the crisis and the corresponding extent of the banks' liabilities.
In
fact, that is a lame rationalization, as Jan Kregel notes in this
interview. Kregel correctly points out that we've seen this show before
in Asia during the financial crisis of 1997-98.
The normal
scenario for a developing country financial crisis would involve
domestic firms borrowing in foreign currency from foreign banks at
interest rates that are reset at a short rollover period. Note that it
makes little difference if the loans have a short or long maturity, the
point is the change in interest costs on cash flows produced by the
short reset interval for interest rates. Short reset periods mean that a
rise in foreign interest rates is quickly transformed into an increased
cash flow commitment for the borrower, instantly reducing margins of
safety.
If the change in international interest rate
differentials leads to a depreciation of the domestic currency relative
to the borrowed foreign currency, then the cushion of safety is further
eroded by the increase in the domestic currency value of the cash
commitments and the principal to be repaid at maturity. And finally, if
the government responds to the weakness of the domestic currency in
international markets by raising interest rates, then this clearly will
make the situation even worse.
As Kregel points out, all of these
conditions pertained in 1997-98, but what gave the crisis particularly
formidable force was the used of customized over-the-counter (OTC)
derivatives, most of which masked the nature of the true risks being
undertaken by the borrower, as well as understating the extent of the
credit exposures. In many instances, these derivatives were structured
in such a way as to avoid the national prudential regulatory guidelines
in the country concerned. In some instances, there was no market
involved in these contracts, which may involve the stipulation of
standard futures and options contracts outside the organized market on a
bilateral basis with individual clients.
However, the majority
of OTC activity involves individually tailored, often highly complex,
combinations of standard financial instruments, packaged together with
derivative contracts designed to meet the particular needs of clients.
These contract packages involve very little direct lending by banks to
clients, and thus generate little net interest income. However, since
they are often executed through special purpose vehicles (such as
specialized investment firms that are independently capitalized), they
have the advantage under the Basel capital adequacy rules of requiring
little or no capital, or of being classified as off-balance-sheet items,
because they do not represent a direct risk exposure for the bank. In
addition, they generate substantial fee and commission income.
Rather
than committing their own capital in these transactions, the banks
serve as intermediaries whose services involve not only matching
borrowers and lenders, but also acting as market innovators to create
investment vehicles that attract lenders and borrowers. Nonetheless,
these activities often require banks to accept some of the risks
associated with the derivatives created in order to produce packages
with the characteristics desired by final borrowers and lenders. But in
many instances, the derivatives themselves are so complex and so
inadequately "stress-tested" that their destructive effects can only be
seen after the fact, which was clearly the case, both in 2008 and the
earlier Asian financial crisis.
The other common feature that
Kregel notes is that the major objective of active, global financial
institutions no longer is the maximization of profits by seeking the
lowest cost funds and channeling them to the highest risk-adjusted
return. Rather, they are most interested in maximizing the amount of
funds intermediated in order to maximize fees and commissions, thereby
maximizing the rate of return on bank capital. This means a shift from
continuous risk assessment and risk monitoring of funded investment
projects that produce recurring flows of interest payments over time, to
the identification of riskless "trades" that produce large, single
payments with as much of the residual risk as possible carried by the
purchasers of the package.
The upshot is that most derivative
packages mask the actual risk involved in an investment and increase the
difficulty in assessing the final return on funds provided.
Kregel discusses all of these factors in great detail in this video
why worry, your government is working for you, this is what you voted for....
ReplyDelete